Market Efficiency in spot and futures Market of precious metal

Paper details

Chose an asset to test market Efficiency in The Derivatives Market for market efficiency in the spot and futures market. use time series data on the spot and futures price of their

asset obtained from Bloomberg, Google Finance or Data Stream. Students will be introduced to the concepts of unit root testing and co-integration analysis, to how these techniques can be easily

applied in Excel. Find data of spot and future price from Bloomberg and use Eviews to do the unit root testing and co-integration test. Key reading: Dougherty, C. (2011). Introduction to

Econometrics (4th Edition). Oxford University Press.Chapter 13.

Arbitrage, Risk Premium, and
Cointegration Tests of the
Efficiency of Futures Markets
Ying-Foon Chow*

  1. INTRODUCTION
    The aim of this article is to provide a new perspective on testing
    the efficiency of commodity futures markets. As discussed in
    Fama and French (1987), there are two popular theories on
    commodity futures prices. The risk premium hypothesis splits a
    futures price into a forecast for a future spot price and an
    expected risk premium. The cost-of-carry model, or the theory
    of storage, assigns the difference between the current spot and
    futures prices to interest foregone in storing the commodity,
    warehousing costs, and a convenience yield from holding an
    inventory. Using various aspects of these two models, many
    empirical studies have tested the efficiency of futures markets.
    The issue of efficiency, however, still remains unresolved, due
    in part to the use of different methodologies and sample
    periods.
    The lack of a generally accepted model of the risk premium
    and convenience yield, as well as the need to work with a
    Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 28(5) & (6), June/July 2001, 0306-686X
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd. 2001, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK
    and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. 693
  • The author is from the Department of Finance, The Chinese University of Hong Kong.
    He is grateful to Gary Koop, Thomas McCurdy, Angelo Melino, Peter Pauly, and especially
    James Pesando for many discussions and comments. He also wishes to thank the Editor,
    two anonymous referees, Eric Chang, Roger Huang, Raymond Kan, Michael McAleer,
    Hua Zhang, Xiaodong Zhu, and seminar participants at the Bank of Canada, the Chinese
    University of Hong Kong, the University of Toronto and the University of Western
    Australia for helpful comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are the author’s
    own. (Paper received November 1998, revised and accepted August 2000)
    Address for correspondence: Ying-Foon Chow, Department of Finance, The Chinese
    University of Homg Kong, Shatin, New Territories, Hong Kong.
    e-mail: [email protected]
    stationary time series, have prevented the authors of many past
    studies from conducting general tests of the Efficient Market
    Hypothesis (EMH) in futures markets. While applying the
    difference operator to each variable can achieve stationarity in
    the data, this imposes too many unit roots in the system if the
    variables are cointegrated, thereby rendering standard methods
    of statistical inference inappropriate. To properly account for the
    non-stationary time series, researchers have begun to use the
    cointegration framework developed by Engle and Granger
    (1987) to test for market efficiency since the 1990s, e.g.,
    MacDonald and Taylor (1988), Sephton and Cochrane (1991),
    Chowdhury (1991), Krehbiel and Adkins (1993) and Moore and
    Cullen (1995). Based on recent developments in econometric
    techniques for models with non-stationary variables, this article
    exploits the non-stationarity of interest rates, spot and futures
    prices to test the EMH using data on levels in a cointegration
    framework.
    The analysis in this article is of interest for several reasons.
    First, Park and Phillips (1989) have shown that a stationary
    variable can be omitted from a cointegrating regression without
    affecting the consistency of the coefficient estimates nor the
    power of statistical procedures for hypothesis testing. In the
    context of a conventional risk premium hypothesis, if the
    subsequent realized spot price is regressed on the futures price
    and a risk premium, the order of variability of the non-stationary
    futures price should dominate the variability of the risk
    premium, which is usually assumed to be stationary. The tests
    in this article thus allow a significant weakening of the usual
    assumption of a constant risk premium, thereby contrasting with
    more general tests which consider a joint hypothesis of market
    efficiency and the specific identification of a risk premium in the
    futures market. In a similar spirit, the theory of storage can be
    tested directly without specifically identifying the dynamics of the
    carrying cost, which include the convenience yield and are
    typically assumed to be stationary. In particular, this article notes
    that the theory of storage can be viewed as a special case of the
    risk premium hypothesis where the `risk premium’ is identified as
    the interest rate. Finally, the methodology is used to examine the
    issue of cross-market or semi-strong form efficiency in the
    commodity futures markets.
    694 CHOW
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    In the following, the EMH and its implications for futures
    markets are briefly discussed in Section 2, with Sub-sections 2(i)
    and 2(ii) presenting the two alternative hypotheses in terms of a
    cointegrated system. Section 3 describes the data used in this
    article. As discussed in Engle and Granger (1987), the first stage
    in testing cointegration between variables is to determine the
    order of integration for an individual time series. The results for
    different tests of a unit root are reported in Section 4. As the null
    hypothesis of a unit root cannot be rejected for the series
    considered, the tests of cointegration and parameter restrictions
    are reported in Section 5. Empirical findings on the issue of
    cross-market efficiency are discussed in Section 6, followed by
    concluding remarks.
  1. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS AND COINTEGRATION
    As mentioned above, there are two popular models of commodity
    futures prices. While the cost-of-carry view of futures prices is not
    controversial as stated in Fama and French (1987), the risk
    premium hypothesis has been the subject of a long and
    continuing controversy. However, these models should be viewed
    as complementary rather than competing views of futures
    pricing. In the following, these two models are briefly discussed.
    In particular, their alternative formulations in the cointegration
    framework and parameter restrictions implied by the EMH are
    presented.
    (i) Testing the Risk Premium Hypothesis: A Restatement
    Under the conventional risk premium hypothesis as in Fama and
    French (1987), the test of market efficiency in a futures market
    can be examined based on the empirical model:
    st‡k ˆ 0 ‡ 1ft;t‡k ‡ 2t;t‡k ‡ t‡k ; …1†
    where ft;t‡k is the (logarithmic) price of a k-period futures
    contract at time t, st‡k is the (logarithmic) spot price of an asset at
    time t ‡ k, t;t‡k is the mean zero time-varying component of the
    k-period risk premium, and t‡k is a mean zero shock
    uncorrelated with any information publicly available at time t.
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 695
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    Market efficiency implies that the error term t‡k should be
    orthogonal to the time t information set, and a testable
    restriction that 0 ˆ Et…t;t‡k †, 1 ˆ 1 and 2 ˆ 1. Note that
    equation (1) obviously requires a model of the risk premium,
    thus the null hypothesis of interest can be re-stated as follows: (a)
    the futures market is informationally efficient, and (b) the risk
    premium is identified by a given pricing model for the futures
    market.
    The theory of cointegrated processes as in Engle and Granger
    (1987) yields a very simple but robust test of a necessary condition
    for market efficiency which does not require identification of the
    risk premium in the conventional framework. The risk premium
    has been typically considered (covariance) stationary on
    theoretical grounds. On the other hand, levels of spot and
    futures prices have been found to follow processes with very
    persistent shocks, or I…1† in the literature. We can then see that
    cointegration between st‡k and ft;t‡k in the form of:
    st‡k ˆ 0 ‡ 1ft;t‡k ‡ ut‡k ; …2†
    where ut‡k ˆ 2t;t‡k ‡ t‡k , is a necessary condition for market
    efficiency under the conventional risk premium hypothesis:
    Assuming the risk premium is stationary, if st‡k and ft;t‡k are not
    cointegrated, then that implies st‡k and ft;t‡k will tend to deviate
    without bounds. It follows that ft;t‡k has little or no power to
    predict the movement of st‡k , which is clearly inconsistent with
    the EMH in the context of futures markets.
    Furthermore, from equation (1) and under the hypothesis that
    st‡k and ft;t‡k are cointegrated, the excess return on a futures
    contract may be expressed as:
    st‡k ÿ ft;t‡k ˆ 0 ‡ 2t;t‡k ‡ wt‡k ;
    where wt‡k ˆ … 1 ÿ 1†ft;t‡k ‡ t‡k . If ft;t‡k is I…1† and 1 6ˆ 1, then
    it follows that wt‡k is also I…1†. This can be interpreted as
    implying that new information is not incorporated into the
    market price. That is, the information which causes the forecast
    (ft;t‡k ) and the realisation (st‡k ) to diverge is not incorporated
    into subsequent forecasts (i.e., ft‡i‡kjt‡i). It follows that market
    efficiency, given that the risk premium is stationary, corresponds
    to st‡k and ft;t‡k being cointegrated with a cointegrating
    coefficient of one in equation (2).
    696 CHOW
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    It should now be obvious that the cointegration framework
    provides a re-interpretation of past tests of the EMH, particularly
    the commonly tested Unbiased Expectations Hypothesis (UEH)
    which represents a joint test of market efficiency and risk
    neutrality.1 With the presence of stochastic trends in the asset
    prices, together with the assumption of a stationary risk
    premium, the EMH can be examined by testing whether (a)
    the futures and spot prices are cointegrated and (b) 1 ˆ 1 in
    equation (2). Only if one is willing to make the additional
    assumption that the stationary risk premium has a zero mean, can
    the UEH then be tested with the additional restriction of 0 ˆ 0
    in equation (2). Even in this case, however, the existence of a
    serial correlation in the residuals of equation (2) does not
    necessarily constitute evidence against an efficient market
    because the dynamics of the zero mean risk premium are simply
    being transferred to the residuals.
    (ii) Testing the Theory of Storage: An Alternative
    In an effort to reconcile the mixed empirical findings with the
    notion of simple efficiency, Brenner and Kroner (1995) derive
    the conditions for futures market efficiency in the cost-of-carry
    framework. This model uses a no-arbitrage argument by
    factoring in the carrying costs involved in holding an
    underlying asset until maturity. The efficiency of the futures
    market can then be examined based on the following empirical
    model:
    st ÿ ft;t‡k ˆ 0 ‡ 1Rt;t‡k ‡ 2Ct;t‡k ‡ “t; …3†
    where st and ft;t‡k are defined as before, Rt;t‡k ˆ krt;t‡k is the
    continuously compounded rate of return on a k-period risk-free
    bond at time t which pays one dollar at time t ‡ k, and
    Ct;t‡k ˆ kct;t‡k is the continuously compounded k-period net cash
    flow yield accruing to the marginal holder of the spot inventory.
    Since the expected return of a hedged position in any
    commodity market should equal the risk-free return, such a noarbitrage condition implies 1 ˆ ÿ1 and 2 ˆ 1. Observe that,
    just as in equation (1) of the risk premium hypothesis, equation
    (3) also requires a model for the convenience yield before the
    model can be formally tested.
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 697
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    The cointegration theory, however, also provides an alternative
    way of examining the cost-of-carry model. As in the case of an
    unobserved risk premium, Brenner and Kroner (1995) argued
    that the (net) convenience yields on holding an asset have
    traditionally been assumed to be stationary. Therefore, assuming
    all variables are I…1† except the Ct;t‡k term, then the results of
    Park and Phillips (1989) imply that the efficiency of the futures
    market can be examined based on the model:
    st ˆ 0 ‡ 1ft;t‡k ‡ 2Rt;t‡k ‡ vt; …4†
    with a testable restriction of 1 ˆ 1 and 2 ˆ ÿ1. It should be
    noted that the constant term ( 0) reflects the marking-to-market
    effect in a futures market and therefore, as argued in Brenner
    and Kroner (1995), need not be zero. The error term (vt) should
    be serially uncorrelated for simple' efficiency; i.e., profitable arbitrage deviations should not be predictable based on past information. However, the error term in model (4) may not be serially uncorrelated if the convenience yield is serially correlated, but this does not imply persistent risk-free arbitrage profit opportunities. An important result from Engle and Granger (1987) is that if any variables are cointegrated, then they are cointegrated at any lead or lag as well. Therefore, if …st; ft;t‡k ; Rt;t‡k † are cointegrated, then the efficiency of a commodity futures market can be tested in the cost-of-carry framework using the model: st‡k ˆ 0 ‡ 1ft;t‡k ‡ 2Rt;t‡k ‡ vt‡k ; …5† where a necessary condition for futures market efficiency is that …st‡k ; ft;t‡k ; Rt;t‡k † be cointegrated with 1 ˆ 1 and 2 ˆ ÿ1 in equation (5). Interestingly, we can view this result as a special case of the risk premium hypothesis by comparing equation (5) and equation (1). The risk premium in previous studies is typically identified through some general equilibrium asset pricing model and thus is (covariance) stationary by construction. In the cost-of-carry framework, therisk premium’
    is essentially identified as the interest rate, i.e., t;t‡k ˆ ÿRt;t‡k .
    That is, the risk premium will have time series properties
    identical to the interest rate under the no-arbitrage condition.
    Despite an inconclusive investigation as to whether interest rates
    contain unit roots, it is generally agreed that they are strongly
    698 CHOW
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    persistent in levels. If, however, interest rates are better
    approximated with a near-unit root process, then, from the
    discussions of equation (2), it is indeed possible to find that the
    futures price is not cointegrated with the realised spot price, or
    they are cointegrated but the cointegrating coefficient is not
    equal to one due to the omission of a relevant variable.
  2. DATA
    Four precious metals with a lengthy history of futures contract
    delivery periods ± gold, silver, palladium and platinum ± are
    chosen here for investigation. Since the price of precious metal
    futures is generally an increasing function of the time to
    maturity, it can be shown that upon maturity the benefits from
    holding the asset (including convenience yield and net of storage
    costs) are less than the risk-free rate. Therefore, it is assumed that
    contracts mature on the first Wednesday of the delivery month as
    in Pindyck (1993). A contract price may sometimes be
    constrained by exchange-imposed limits on daily price moves.
    In those cases, prices for the preceding Tuesday are used. If those
    prices likewise hit the limit-move, prices for the following
    Thursday are used, or if those are constrained, the preceding
    Monday and then the following Friday are chosen. In all cases,
    the settlement price of the gold and silver contracts traded on the
    Commodity Exchange Inc., as well as the palladium and platinum
    futures contracts traded on the New York Mercantile Exchange,
    are collected from the Commodity System Inc. databank.
    Constant-to-maturity futures contracts of one-month maturity
    are collected for gold and silver, and three-month maturity
    contracts are collected for palladium and platinum. That is, the
    futures prices ft;t‡k are obtained for k ˆ 1 (gold and silver) and 3
    (palladium and platinum). Following the tradition of the
    literature, the spot price st is measured by the price of the
    corresponding maturing contract. Thus both the spot and futures
    prices and the time interval between the two delivery dates are
    known for exactly the same commodity. It should be noted that
    the number of observations of the constant-to-maturity contracts
    is always less than the number of months in the sample period,
    since the futures contracts do not mature each month.
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 699
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    The risk-free rate series is defined as the interest rate on a US
    Treasury bill (T-bill) that matures nearest to the trading of the
    relevant futures contract. Therefore, the holding periods for the
    T-bill and the futures contract are matched as closely as possible.
    The data are extracted from the Center for Research on Security
    Prices (CRSP) bond data tape. The sample period for all series is
    February 1975 to February 2000 for gold, February 1970 to
    February 2000 for silver, June 1977 to March 2000 for palladium
    and April 1970 to April 2000 for platinum. Descriptive statistics of
    the data are presented in Table 1. Finally, with the exception of
    the interest rates, the price series used in this article are the
    natural logarithmic values of the actual prices.
    Table 1
    Descriptive Statistics of the Data
    Market Variable N Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max.
    Gold Spot Price 301 344.88 108.11 104.80 713.00
    Futures Price 346.40 109.89 105.00 695.50
    Interest Rate (%) 0.55 0.23 0.22 1.35
    Silver Spot Price 361 602.02 427.38 130.00 3885.00
    Futures Price 602.30 411.35 130.40 3637.00
    Interest Rate (%) 0.53 0.22 0.22 1.35
    Palladium Spot Price 92 143.25 90.01 42.40 690.90
    Futures Price 136.67 68.81 43.00 394.50
    Interest Rate (%) 1.77 0.73 0.75 4.01
    Platinum Spot Price 121 348.92 146.97 101.20 806.50
    Futures Price 349.89 147.17 102.50 722.60
    Interest Rate (%) 1.69 0.68 0.68 3.85
    Notes:
    The gold and platinum contracts are quoted in dollars per troy ounce, the silver contracts
    are quoted in cents per troy ounce, and the palladium contracts are quoted in dollars per
    ounce. The standard delivery months are February, April, June, August, October and
    December for gold; January, March, May, July, September and December for silver;
    March, June, September and December for palladium; and January, April, July and
    October for platinum. In addition, there are monthly supplemental contracts in gold and
    silver to fill in the months between the standard contracts.
    700 CHOW
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
  3. TESTS OF UNIT ROOT AND STATIONARITY
    Before estimating cointegrating regressions, it is conventional to
    test the order of integration for the variables used. The
    augmented Dicky±Fuller (ADF) tests are often used in the
    literature to test for the possible existence of unit roots.
    Alternatively, as in this article, one can use the non-parametric
    Zt and Za tests of Phillips and Perron (1988), which allow for
    heterogeneously distributed, and possibly dependent, innovation
    sequences in the series considered. To examine the possible
    existence of deterministic trends in the data, the testing strategy
    suggested by Dolado, Jenkinson and Sosvilla-Rivero (1990) is
    used in choosing the appropriate regression model. The longrun' variance of the regression residuals is estimated using the optimal bandwidth selection procedure of Andrews and Monahan (1992). Furthermore, the first-order autoregression prewhitened QS kernel estimator is used for Zt and Za tests, since Maekawa (1994) shows that the prewhitened kernel estimator significantly improves the performance of these unit root tests. On the other hand, it is at least conceptually preferable to test for the stationarity of an observed time series since many other tests have failed to reject the null hypothesis of integration. In particular, the frequency of incorrect conclusions is decreased when a test of stationarity is conducted in conjunction with a standard unit root test, relative to the application of unit root tests alone. The G…0; q† test proposed in Park (1990) and the  test proposed in Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt and Shin (1992) for the null hypothesis of level stationary series are conducted here tocross validate’ the unit root tests, after the procedure of
    Dolado, Jenkinson and Sosvilla-Rivero (1990) revealed no
    evidence of a trend in the series considered. As suggested in
    Ogaki and Park (1997), q is chosen to be 3 for the G…0; q† test.
    The results of the Zt, Za, G…0; 3† and  tests are reported in
    Table 2. The results from the ADF tests are similar to the Zt and
    Za tests, and are therefore not reported here. These results are
    consistent with the hypothesis that the data considered have only
    one unit root. While not reported here, the first difference in all
    series considered significantly rejects the null hypothesis of a unit
    root.
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 701
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    Table 2
    Tests of Unit Roots
    Regression model: yt ˆ 0 ‡ 1ytÿ1 ‡ ut
    H0: Unit Root H0: Level Stationary
    Zt Za G(0,3) 
    Gold Spot ÿ2.017 ÿ6.369 11.175 0.412z
    (0.280) (0.316) (0.011)
    Futures ÿ1.965 ÿ6.100 11.067 0.419z
    (0.302) (0.336) (0.011)
    Interest rate ÿ2.050 ÿ9.674 10.119 0.603y
    (0.266) (0.143) (0.018)
    Silver Spot ÿ2.347 ÿ8.899 13.870 0.374y
    (0.158) (0.173) (0.003)
    Futures ÿ2.329 ÿ8.586 13.806 0.382y
    (0.164) (0.187) (0.003)
    Interest rate ÿ2.383 ÿ9.934 8.164 0.382y
    (0.147) (0.135) (0.043)
    Palladium Spot ÿ0.633 ÿ2.433 15.093 0.771*
    (0.857) (0.722) (0.002)
    Futures ÿ1.337 ÿ5.050 13.806 0.704y
    (0.609) (0.421) (0.003)
    Interest rate ÿ2.025 ÿ7.587 12.371 1.032*
    (0.276) (0.229) (0.006)
    Platinum Spot ÿ1.470 ÿ4.033 7.086 0.532y
    (0.546) (0.529) (0.069)
    Futures ÿ1.618 ÿ4.333 6.922 0.523y
    (0.470) (0.496) (0.074)
    Interest rate ÿ2.328 ÿ10.014 8.678 0.400z
    (0.165) (0.127) (0.034)
    Notes:
    The p-values are reported in parentheses. The p-values for the Zt and Za tests are
    computed using the results of MacKinnon (1996); while G(0,3) has an asymptotic 2…3†
    distribution under the null hypothesis. The 1%, 5% and 10% critical values of the
    Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt and Shin (1992)  test are 0.739, 0.463 and 0.347, so *, y
    and z indicate the rejection of the null hypothesis at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels. The
    regression model is chosen by the testing strategy suggested in Dolado, Jenkinson and
    Sosvilla-Rivero (1990). The `long-run’ variance of ut is estimated using the QS kernel with
    the optimal bandwidth selection procedure of Andrews and Monahan (1992), and a firstorder autoregression prewhitening method for the Zt and Za , tests as suggested in
    Maekawa (1994).
    702 CHOW
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
  4. TESTS OF COINTEGRATION & PARAMETER RESTRICTIONS
    (i) Tests of Cointegration
    The residual-based Zt and Za tests of Phillips and Ouliaris (1990)
    are first conducted to assess the adequacy of the cointegrating
    models (2) and (5) over the sample period. Again, the long-run' variance of the regression residuals is estimated using the prewhitened QS kernel estimator with the optimal bandwidth selection procedure of Andrews and Monahan (1992). Note that these tests address the question of testing the null hypothesis of no cointegration rather than cointegration between the variables considered. Since the hypothesis of cointegration is of primary interest, it is often argued that cointegration would be a more natural choice of the null hypothesis. Therefore, the variableaddition H…p; q† test of Park (1990) and the residual-based C test of Shin (1994) are used to test cointegration as the null hypothesis for the models (2) and (5). As discussed in Ogaki and Park (1997), the H…0; q† statistic tests the deterministic cointegration restriction, while the H…1; q† statistic tests for stochastic cointegration between variables, and the choice of q should be small. Therefore, following Ogaki and Park (1997), the H…0; 1† and H…1; 3† tests are performed in this article. The results of the above tests are presented in Table 3. The results of the Zt and Za tests seem to support the alternative of cointegration between futures and spot prices in all markets with or without the interest rates. The direct tests of cointegration also imply similar results: Under the assumption that the variables are stochastically cointegrated, the deterministic cointegration restriction cannot be rejected in all markets for both models in terms of the H…0; 1† tests. The results of the H…1; 3† tests for stochastic cointegration indicate that the cointegration hypothesis can be rejected for the palladium and the platinum markets in both the stationary risk premium framework and the cost-of-carry framework. In addition, the C tests cannot reject cointegration in model (2) for all markets, while model (5) is rejected marginally for the silver market. Although the results may seem to indicate a certainfragility’ in
    the cointegration hypothesis, there is evidence to support the
    idea that both model (2) and model (5) are cointegrated systems.
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 703
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    Table 3
    Tests of Cointegration
    Model (2): st ˆ 0 ‡ 1ftÿk;t ‡ ut
    H0: No Cointegration H0: Cointegration
    Zt Za H(0,1) H(1,3) C
    Gold ÿ14.720 ÿ257.040 0.569 0.244 0.085
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.451) (0.885)
    Silver ÿ16.025 ÿ305.723 0.175 3.114 0.064
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.676) (0.211)
    Palladium ÿ8.840 ÿ86.676 2.210 7.796 0.184
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.137) (0.020)
    Platinum ÿ10.682 ÿ118.926 1.690 6.770 0.185
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.194) (0.034)
    Model (5): st ˆ 0 ‡ 1ftÿk;t ‡ 2Rtÿk;t ‡ vt
    H0: No Cointegration H0: Cointegration
    Zt Za H(0,1) H(1,3) C
    Gold ÿ14.764 ÿ257.859 0.444 2.448 0.128
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.505) (0.294)
    Silver ÿ16.226 ÿ309.625 0.885 3.072 0.209z
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.347) (0.215)
    Palladium ÿ9.035 ÿ87.456 0.533 9.860 0.144
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.465) (0.007)
    Platinum ÿ11.060 ÿ123.699 0.979 9.508 0.110
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.322) (0.009)
    Notes:
    The p-values are reported in parentheses. The p-values for the Zt and Za tests are
    computed using the results of MacKinnon (1996); while H…p; q† has an asymptotic
    2…q ÿ p† distribution under the null hypothesis. The 1%, 5% and 10% critical values of
    Shin (1994) C test are 0.533, 0.314 and 0.231 for model (2), and 0.380, 0.221 and 0.163
    for model (5), so z indicates the rejection of the null hypothesis at the 10% level. The
    long-run' covariance parameters of ut and vt are estimated using the QS kernel with the optimal bandwidth selection procedure of Andrews and Monahan (1992), and a firstorder autoregression prewhitening method for the Zt and Za tests, as suggested in Maekawa (1994). 704 CHOW ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001 This indicates that the futures price can indeed help predict about the future movements of the spot price in terms of the conventional risk premium hypothesis represented by model (2). While in the cost-of-carry framework of model (5), the variables comprising the no-arbitrage condition do seem to form a stationary equilibrium in the long run. (ii) Tests of Parameter Restriction Despite their popularity, however, a limitation of the Engle± Granger type of residual-based tests, such as the Zt and Za tests above, is that no strong statistical inference can be drawn with respect to the parameters, e.g., 1 and 2 in model (5), which are the main interest here. Although the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimator can be shown to be super-consistent under cointegration, Stock (1987) has argued that the estimated standard errors may be misleading for hypothesis testing. There have been several procedures developed recently to estimate long-run relationships, which allow one to formally conduct asymptotic chi-square tests on the cointegrating parameters. The dynamic OLS (DOLS) methodology of Stock and Watson (1993) is used here, since Stock and Watson (1993) and Montalvbo (1995) suggest that the DOLS estimator performs systematically better than the other estimators based on Monte Carlo simulation experiments. The parameter estimates and the hypothesis test results of model (2) are reported in the upper panel of Table 4. It can be seen that the estimates for 1 are very close to the hypothesized value of one, ranging from 0.997 (gold) to 1.036 (palladium). Observe that the estimates of 0 are fairly close to zero, ranging from ÿ0:181 (palladium) to 0.010 (gold). Thus, it may be of interest to see if there is any support for theunbiased
    expectations’ hypothesis where 1 ˆ 1 and 0 ˆ 0 in model (2).
    It can be seen that this hypothesis is significantly rejected in all
    markets. As often argued in the literature, such rejections do not
    mean that the markets are inefficient. Rather, it is more likely
    that the risk premium, if stationary, has a non-zero mean over
    time. However, the hypothesis that 1 ˆ 1 is also rejected for all
    markets except the silver market. Therefore, it seems that the
    futures markets for these precious metals do not conform to the
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 705
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    necessary condition of the EMH under the risk premium model
    (2).
    The lower panel of Table 4 reports the parameter estimates
    and test results of the cost-of-carry model (5). The estimates of 1
    are again very close to the hypothesized value of one, ranging
    from 0.999 (gold) to 1.026 (palladium). On the other hand,
    there is a considerable variation in the estimates of 2, ranging
    Table 4
    Tests of Cointegrating Parameters
    Model (2): st ˆ 0 ‡ 1ftÿk;t ‡ ut
    H0 : 0 ˆ 0
    b0 b1 H0 : 1 ˆ 1 and 1 ˆ 1
    Gold 0.010 0.997 ÿ2.248 164.989
    [0.007] 0.001 (<0.001)
    Silver ÿ0.008 1.000 0.206 36.628
    [0.011] 0.002 (<0.001)
    Palladium ÿ0.181 1.036 3.020 17.059
    [0.057] 0.012 (<0.001)
    Platinum ÿ0.082 1.012 2.711 63.653
    [0.025] 0.004 (<0.001)
    Model (5): st ˆ 0 ‡ 1ftÿk;t ‡ 2Rtÿk;t ‡ vt
    H0 : 1 ˆ 1
    b0 b1 b2 H0 : 1 ˆ 1 H0 : 2 ˆ ÿ1 and 2 ˆ ÿ1
    Gold 0.003 0.999 ÿ1.070 ÿ0.429 ÿ0.480 0.616
    [0.005] [0.001] 0.145 (0.631) (0.735)
    Silver ÿ0.033 1.006 ÿ2.048 2.992 ÿ1.949 8.996
    [0.011] [0.002] 0.538 (0.052) (0.011)
    Palladium ÿ0.111 1.026 ÿ1.098 2.306 ÿ0.245 6.576
    [0.057] [0.011] 0.401 (0.808) (0.037)
    Platinum ÿ0.083 1.016 ÿ1.365 4.609 ÿ1.406 21.368
    [0.020] [0.003] 0.260 (0.163) (<0.001)
    Notes:
    The standard errors and p-values are, respectively, reported in brackets and parentheses.
    The standard errors are calculated using the method outlined in Stock and Watson
    (1993).
    706 CHOW
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    from ÿ1:098 (palladium) to ÿ2:048 (silver). The hypothesis that
    1 ˆ 1 and 2 ˆ ÿ1 jointly is then tested under the assumption
    of a stationary convenience yield. While this hypothesis is not
    rejected for the gold market, it is rejected for the other markets
    under conventional significance levels. The hypotheses that
    1 ˆ 1 and 2 ˆ ÿ1 are also tested individually. It can be seen
    from Table 4 that 1 ˆ 1 can be rejected in all markets except the
    gold market. This may indicate that the futures price is not an
    unbiased estimate of the future spot price for these markets. On
    the other hand, despite the relatively high standard errors of the
    estimates, the hypothesis of 2 ˆ ÿ1 can only be rejected
    marginally for the silver market and cannot be rejected for the
    other metals. Based on these results, one might conclude that the
    no-arbitrage condition is not satisfied in at least one market
    considered here.
    In summary, when comparing the results in Table 4, it can be
    seen that while the gold futures market may not be consistent
    with the EMH under the risk premium framework, it is consistent
    with the no-arbitrage condition as implied by the cost-of-carry
    model. On the other hand, even though the no-arbitrage
    condition is rejected in the silver market, such results do not
    indicate market inefficiencies. Rather, it is more likely that the
    risk premium model is more appropriate than the cost-of-carry
    model for the silver futures market. However, the results in Table
    4 do indicate that neither the risk premium hypothesis nor the
    cost-of-carry framework could model the platinum futures market
    satisfactorily.
  5. TESTS OF CROSS-MARKET EFFICIENCY
    Using data from the London Metal Exchange, Hsieh and
    Kulatilaka (1982) and Canarella and Pollard (1986) provided
    multi-market tests of market efficiency, arguing that the metals
    under study are traded in the same location and hence a wider
    view of efficiency is required. The issue examined in these studies
    was whether past forecast errors across markets are useful in
    predicting errors in other markets, since traders should be aware
    of activities across the exchange. That is, the multi-market test
    may be considered a semi-strong form test. Since the tests in this
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 707
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    article allow for risk premiums to be incorporated in the error
    term and the intercept, the models used here will provide less
    ambiguous tests of market efficiency.
    As the maturity cycle for palladium contracts does not
    correspond to that of platinum, we shall concentrate on crossmarket efficiency in the gold and silver markets instead. It is
    commonly believed that there may be a stable or semi-stable longrun relationship between these prices. If they are then
    cointegrated, however, the extent to which either can be forecast
    is expected to be limited due to the standard EMH. Thus, if gold
    and silver prices are indeed generated by an efficient market,
    they cannot move closely together in the long-run, or one can be
    used to help forecast the other as argued in Escribano and
    Granger (1998).
    We first test if gold and silver prices are cointegrated in either
    the spot or the futures market with the following cointegrating
    regressions:
    s
    i
    t ˆ 0 ‡ 1s
    j
    t ‡ us
    t ; …6†
    f i
    t;t‡1 ˆ 0 ‡ 1f
    j
    t;t‡1 ‡ uf
    t ; …7†
    for i; j ˆ gold and silver. The results presented in Table 5 show
    strong support of the EMH in that there is no evidence of
    cointegration between the gold and silver prices in either market.
    These results are consistent with that of Escribano and Granger
    (1998), who found that cointegration between these prices could
    have occurred during some periods between 1971 to 1990, but
    the two markets are becoming separated thereafter.
    Now we turn to the issue of multi-market efficiency in the
    futures markets. To this end, Table 6 presents the results of the
    following regressions:
    s
    i
    t‡1 ˆ 0 ‡ 1f i
    t;t‡1 ‡ 2f
    j
    t;t‡1 ‡ ut‡1; …8†
    for i; j ˆ gold and silver. The results of the no-cointegration tests
    in the top panel of Table 6 seem to support the alternative of
    cointegration in equation (8). The direct tests of cointegration,
    however, provide somewhat contradictory evidence: Although
    the H…0; 1† tests indicate that a deterministic cointegration
    restriction cannot be rejected in either market when the variables
    are assumed to be stochastically cointegrated, the H…1; 3† tests
    708 CHOW
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    indicate that the hypothesis of stochastic cointegration among
    these variables can be rejected at conventional levels. On the
    other hand, the C tests indicate that the null hypothesis of
    cointegration cannot be rejected.
    The lower panel of Table 6 provides a possible explanation of
    such findings. The joint hypothesis that 1 ˆ 1 and 2 ˆ 0 cannot
    be rejected in either market under conventional significance
    levels, and the same conclusions can also be made when the
    hypotheses that 1 ˆ 1 and 2 ˆ 0 are tested individually. Note
    that with the addition of the silver futures price, as in the case of
    model (5), the gold futures price is now an unbiased estimator of
    Table 5
    Tests of Cointegration Across Spot Markets and Futures Markets
    Equation (6): si
    t ˆ 0 ‡ 1s
    j
    t ‡ us
    t
    Dependent H0: No Cointegration H0: Cointegration
    Variable
    Zt Za H(0,1) H(1,3) C
    Gold ÿ1.510 ÿ3.374 23.659 101.606 0.265z
    (0.759) (0.853) (<0.001) (<0.001)
    Silver ÿ2.243 ÿ9.944 6.909 111.831 0.257z
    (0.403) (0.362) (0.009) (<0.001)
    Equation (7): f i
    t;t‡1 ˆ 0 ‡ 1f
    j
    t;t‡1 ‡ uf
    t
    Dependent H0: No Cointegration H0: Cointegration
    Variable
    Zt Za H(0,1) H(1,3) C
    Gold ÿ1.560 ÿ3.761 26.934 109.868 0.265z
    (0.740) (0.826) (<0.001) (<0.001)
    Silver ÿ2.181 ÿ9.433 6.726 135.356 0.247z
    (0.435) (0.393) (0.009) (<0.001)
    Notes:
    The p-values are reported in parentheses. The p-values for the Zt and Za tests are
    computed using the results of MacKinnon (1996); while H…p; q† has an asymptotic
    2…q ÿ p† distribution under the null hypothesis. The 1%, 5% and 10% critical values of
    Shin (1994) C test are 0.533, 0.314 and 0.231, so z indicates the rejection of the null
    hypothesis at the 10% level. The `long-run’ covariance parameters of us
    t and uf
    t are
    estimated using the QS kernel with the optimal bandwidth selection procedure of
    Andrews and Monahan (1992), and a first-order autoregression prewhitening method for
    the Zt and Za tests, as suggested in Maekawa (1994).
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 709
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    the future spot price. Nevertheless, these results imply that while
    the futures price from the other market may seem to co-move
    with the own spot price, such co-movements are statistically and
    economically insignificant and may even be spurious. Therefore,
    we still cannot reject the restrictions associated with market
    efficiency for the gold and silver markets.
  6. CONCLUDING REMARKS
    To account for the non-stationarity in the data, this article has
    applied recently developed econometric techniques to a test of
    the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) in the conventional risk
    Table 6
    Cointegration Tests of Multi-market Efficiency
    Equation (8): si
    t‡1 ˆ 0 ‡ 1f i
    t;t‡1 ‡ 2f
    j
    t;t‡1 ‡ ut
    Dependent H0: No Cointegration H0 : Cointegration
    Variable
    Zt Za H(0,1) H(1,3) C
    Gold ÿ14.705 ÿ256.677 0.002 4.938 0.090
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.963) (0.084)
    Silver ÿ14.545 ÿ254.089 0.001 6.144 0.066
    (<0.001) (<0.001) (0.986) (0.046)
    Dependent H0 : 1 ˆ 1
    Variable b0 b1 b2 H0 : 1 ˆ 1 H0 : 2 ˆ 0 and 2 ˆ 0
    Gold 0.030 1.001 ÿ0.006 0.519 ÿ1.213 1.636
    [0.006] [0.001] 0.005 (0.226) (0.441)
    Silver 0.024 0.996 ÿ0.001 ÿ1.261 ÿ0.065 1.625
    [0.018] [0.003] 0.015 (0.948) (0.444)
    Notes:
    The standard errors and p-values are, respectively, reported in brackets and parentheses.
    The p-values for the Zt and Za tests are computed using the results of MacKinnon (1996);
    while H…p; q† has an asymptotic 2…q ÿ p† distribution under the null hypothesis. The 1%,
    5% and 10% critical values of Shin (1994) C test are 0.380, 0.221 and 0.163. The longrun' covariance parameters of ut are estimated using the QS kernel with the optimal bandwidth selection procedure of Andrews and Monahan (1992), and a first-order autoregression prewhitening method for the Zt and Za tests, as suggested in Maekawa (1994). The standard errors are calculated using the method outlined in Stock and Watson (1993). 710 CHOW ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001 premium framework, and to a test of the complementary hypothesis of the no-arbitrage condition in the cost-of-carry framework, for four precious metal futures markets. The cointegration techniques allows one to test market efficiency under both hypotheses without relying on any specific assumed form of the risk premium or the convenience yield, other than the stationary assumption. In addition, it is argued that the costof-carry model (5) can be viewed as a special case of the risk premium model (2) where therisk premium’ is identified as the
    interest rate. As such, the possibility of a non-stationary risk
    premium in the futures market cannot be ruled out since the
    interest rate may be better approximated with a unit root
    distribution. In this case, model (2) is mis-specified and the
    estimates are therefore inconsistent.
    The empirical results show supporting evidence of cointegration among the series considered in all markets. This is
    consistent with a necessary condition for the EMH that the
    futures market provides useful information on future movements
    in the spot market. However, it is found that the parameter
    restrictions are not satisfied for the cointegrating parameters in
    some markets under either the conventional risk premium
    hypothesis (2), or the cost-of-carry model (5), or both. The lack
    of supportive evidence for both the risk premium hypothesis and
    the cost-of-carry model in these futures markets is puzzling. Such
    evidence implies that either the traders of these futures contracts
    ignore the availability of a positive risk-free return ± thus
    rejecting rationality on the part of the participants in these
    markets ± or that there exists an important omitted variable from
    the risk premium or no-arbitrage relationships.
    Finally, it should be noted that although the cointegration
    framework allows one to investigate the long-run relationship
    between non-stationary economic variables such as the ones
    studied here, the cointegrating parameters may not be stable' and are subject to structural changes in the economy in a finite sample. For example, it is well known that US interest rates have experienced monetary regime shifts during the past two decades. Such regime shifts, if unexpected, could have some considerable impacts on the cointegration tests considered here. EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 711 ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001 NOTE 1 The UEH has also been called thesimple efficiency’ hypothesis by Hansen
    and Hodrick (1980) and the speculative efficiency' hypothesis by Bilson (1981). The joint restriction of market efficiency and risk neutrality implies coefficient values of 0 ˆ 0 and 1 ˆ 1, with 2t;t‡k ‡ t‡k  "t‡k being serially uncorrelated in equation (1). REFERENCES Andrews, D.W.K. and J.C. Monahan (1992),An Improved Heteroskedasticity
    and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator,’ Econometrica,
    Vol. 60, pp. 953±66.
    Bilson, J.F.O. (1981), The ``Speculative Efficiency'' Hypothesis,' Journal of Business, Vol. 54, pp. 435±51. Brenner, R.J. and K.F. Kroner (1995),Arbitrage, Cointegration and Testing the
    Unbiasedness Hypothesis in Financial Markets,’ Journal of Financial and
    Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 30, pp. 23±42.
    Canarella, G. and S.K. Pollard (1986), The Efficiency of the London Metal Exchange: A Test with Overlapping and Non-Overlapping Data,' Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 10, pp. 575±93. Chowdury, A.R. (1991),Futures Market Efficiency: Evidence from
    Cointegration Tests,’ Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 11, pp. 577±89.
    Dolado, J.J., T. Jenkinson and S. Sosvilla-Rivero (1990), Cointegration and Unit Roots,' Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 4, pp. 249±73. Engle, R.F. and C.W.J. Granger (1987),Co-Integration and Error Correction:
    Representation, Estimation and Testing,’ Econometrica, Vol. 55, pp. 251±76.
    Escribano, A. and C.W.J. Granger (1998), Investigating the Relationship between Gold and Silver Prices,' Journal of Forecasting, Vol. 17, pp. 81±107. Fama, E.F. and K.R. French (1987),Commodity Futures Prices: Some Evidence
    on Forecast Power, Premiums and the Theory of Storage,’ Journal of
    Business, Vol. 60, pp. 55±73.
    Hansen, L.P. and R.J. Hodrick (1980), Forward Exchange Rates as Optimal Predictors of Future Spot Rates: An Econometric Analysism' Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88, pp. 829±53. Hsieh, D.A. and N. Kulatilaka (1982),Rational Expectations and Risk Premia in
    Forward Markets: Primary Metals at the London Metal Exchange,’ Journal of
    Finance, Vol. 37, pp. 1199±207.
    Krehbiel, T. and L.C. Adkins (1993), Cointegration Tests of the Unbiased Expectations Hypothesis in Metals Markets,' Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 13, pp. 753±63. Kwiatkowski, D., P.C.B. Phillips, P. Schmidt and Y. Shin (1992),Testing the
    Null Hyupothesis of Stationarity Against the Alternative of a Unit Root,’
    Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 54, pp. 159±78.
    MacDonald, R. and M. Taylor (1988), Metals Prices, Efficiency and Cointegration: Some Evidence from the London Metal Exchange,' Bulletin of Economic Research, Vol. 40, pp. 235±39. MacKinnon, J.G. (1996),Numerical Distribution Functions for Unit Root and
    Cointegration Tests,’ Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 11, pp. 601±18.
    Maekawa, K. (1994), Prewhitened Unit Root Test,' Economics Letters, Vol. 45, pp. 712 CHOW ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001 145±53. Montalvo, J.G. (1995),Comparing Cointegrating Regression Estimators: Some
    Additional Monte Carlo Results,’ Economics Letters, Vol. 48, pp. 229±34.
    Moore, M.J. and U. Cullen (1995), Speculative Efficiency on the London Metal Exchange,' The Manchester School, Vol. 63, pp. 235±56. Ogaki, M. and J.Y. Park (1997),A Cointegration Approach to Estimating
    Preference Parameters,’ Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 82, pp. 107±34.
    Park, J.Y. (1990), Testing for Unit Roots and Cointegration by Variable Addition,' in G.F. Rhodes and T.B. Fomby (eds.), Co-Integration, Spurious Regressions, and Unit Roots, Vol. 8 of Advances in Econometrics (JAI Press, Connecticut), pp. 107±33. ________ and P.C.B. Phillips (1989),Statistical Inference in Regressions with
    Integrated Processes: Part 2,’ Econometric Theory, Vol. 5, pp. 95±132.
    Phillips, P.C.B. and S. Ouliaris (1990), Asymptotic Properties of Residual Based Tests for Cointegration,' Econometrica, Vol. 58, pp. 165±93. ________ and P. Perron (1988),Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series
    Regression,’ Biometrika, Vol. 75, pp. 335±46.
    Pindyck, R.S. (1993), The Present Value Model of Rational Commodity Pricing,' Economic Journal, Vol. 103, pp. 511±30. Sephton, P.S. and D.K. Cochrane (1991),The Efficiency of the London Metals
    Exchange: Another Look at the Evidence,’ Applied Economics, Vol. 23, pp.
    669±74.
    Shin, Y. (1994), A Residual-Based Test of the Null of Cointegration Against the Alternative of No Cointegration,' Econometric Theory, Vol. 10, pp. 91±115. Stock, J.H. (1987),Asymptotic Properties of Least Squares Estimators of
    Cointegrating Vectors,’ Econometrica, Vol. 55, pp. 1035±56.
    __ and M.W. Watson (1993), `A Simple Estimator of Cointegrating
    Vectors in Higher Order Integrated Systems,’ Econometrica, Vol. 61, pp.
    783±820.
    EFFICIENCY OF FUTURES MARKETS 713
    ß Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2001
    Copyright of Journal of Business Finance & Accounting is the property of Wiley-Blackwell
    and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without
    the copyright holder’s express written permission. However, users may print, download, or
    email articles for individual use.

This question has been answered.

Get Answer